Book review: The End of an Illusion
Born on the radical
left and then seized by the right, has the concept of “capitalism” outlived its
usefulness? Timothy
Shenk spoke with Fred Block, author of Capitalism: The Future of an Illusion, out now from University
of California Press.
Timothy Shenk: The title of your book—Capitalism: The
Future of an Illusion—is clearly meant to provoke an argument. Why do you
think capitalism is “an illusion”?
Fred Block: The premise of the book is that linguistic
larceny plays a big role in politics. Between 1890 and 1914, reformist
intellectuals in the U.S. and England redefined liberalism from economic
liberalism to political liberalism to justify expanding state action to
constrain market forces. Free-market thinkers protested against the
redefinition, but they were ineffective and the move put them at a huge
disadvantage for many decades. Ultimately, many of the Mont Pelerin types
relabeled themselves as neoliberals. But they got their revenge by stealing the
word capitalism from the left and redefining it as a coherent and unified
system that cannot be modified without a huge loss in economic output. It is
that view of capitalism that I am calling an illusion.
Shenk: I can imagine a sympathetic reader
agreeing that it’s a mistake to talk about capitalism as an unchanging,
hegemonic creature whose operations are dictated by a singular logic but still
balking at the notion of giving up on “capitalism” altogether. You acknowledge
as much in the book, writing that it’s “unrealistic to imagine that people will
stop using the term ‘capitalism’—no matter how strong the arguments against the
term might be.” Are there no definitions of “capitalism” that you think are
acceptable?
Block: My point is that after forty years of the
right successfully defining capitalism in a certain way, developing our own
complicated and more accurate definitions is a fool’s errand. Protestors
holding up signs saying “Down with Capitalism” cannot add a two-page footnote
explaining exactly which definition they are using. Many people who see that
protest sign have already internalized the right’s definition and will assume
the protestors are advocating impractical measures that will make us all poorer.
We should instead be
fighting on the terrain of democracy by arguing that we can make our economy
more productive, more just, and more sustainable by extending and deepening
democracy. The reality is that the right’s successes in limiting democracy by
empowering big money in campaigns, gerrymandering, restricting voting rights,
and undermining unions have the consequence of making our economy less
productive. When democracy is restricted, business opts for predation rather
than efficiency since it is always easier to rip people off than to build a
better mousetrap.
Shenk: You pair this argument about capitalism with a
history that I think will be surprising to younger readers. Through the 1960s,
you write, the term capitalism was freighted with negative connotations, so
much so that even radicals worried that using the word might alienate potential
allies. What was so dangerous about invoking “capitalism”?
Block: During the Cold War, Soviet and Chinese
Communists routinely used the term “capitalism” to denounce the evils of U.S.
society. So in the 1950s, the society’s defenders talked about “free
enterprise” to contrast freedom with communist tyranny. Meanwhile, in response
to McCarthy’s anti-communist crusade, liberals and some radicals did everything
they could to distance themselves from the vocabulary of communist parties. So
in the 1960s, anybody who talked about capitalism risked being seen as part of
the far left.
Shenk: However risky it might have been to talk about
capitalism in the 1960s, by the 1980s that stigma had worn away—and it did so,
you argue, because the term was claimed by the right. Why did conservatives
embrace the concept of capitalism after resisting it for so long?
Block: Actually as early as the 1960s, thinkers
such as Milton Friedman and Ayn Rand started to reclaim the word capitalism for
the right, but they were still way out of the mainstream. The big change
happened late in the 1970s with Irving Kristol, the original neoconservative
intellectual, playing a central role. Kristol had been a Trotskyist at City
College and he knew Marx well. He saw that describing the existing order as a
capitalist system would allow conservatives to insist that any reform
initiatives would produce equal and opposite negative effects. It followed logically
that all the reforms of the New Deal and the Great Society were responsible for
the economic woes of the time, and that massive tax cuts for the rich, rollback
of government programs, and the slashing of regulations were needed to restore
the economy to health.
Shenk: I’m struck by how much emphasis your account
gives to ideas. “Our political leaders are being held hostage,” you write, “by
the illusion that we live within a coherent, unified, and unchangeable
capitalist order.” It’s a powerful argument, but what would you say to a
skeptic who said that who our political leaders were really held hostage to
were donors who care a lot more about the balance in their bank accounts than
they do about the health of capitalism as a whole? Or what about a more sophisticated
version of a similar argument—for instance, that in periods of modest economic
growth, clashes over the distribution of resources will inevitably be intense,
which means that politics will come to seem like a zero-sum game?
Block: I stress ideas because politics is
essentially a battle of ideas. Yes, of course, I recognize the importance of
class power as represented by campaign contributions and threats of
disinvestment. But we also know from Thomas Piketty and others that from 1910
to 1970, radicals and reformers were able to win major victories and diminish
the magnitude of income and wealth inequalities despite that class power. So I
don’t think it is the nature of the system that produces the extreme inequality
that we now have. It is the weakened mobilization of progressive forces, and
part of the explanation for that weakness is the ideological hegemony of
free-market ideas. Challenging those ideas is essential to any effective
mobilization against class power.
Shenk: Are you as skeptical about the uses of
“neoliberalism” as you are of capitalism? The narrative of a welfare state in
retreat over the last forty-odd years is extremely popular with both scholars
and activists, and this simultaneous rollback across much of the globe would
seem to be a problem for an account that gives ideas so much causal weight. Do
you just not buy this narrative?
Block: I agree with the basic narrative, but I
prefer the term “market fundamentalism” for two reasons. First, it highlights
the theological and unfalsifiable nature of their belief system. Second, I
don’t see what is “neo” about their economic liberalism. The original market
liberals—Malthus and Ricardo—also believed in the use of state coercion to
construct a market system.
But I also see the
triumph of market fundamentalism as contingent, rather than a necessary product
of the logic of capitalism. It is here that I put a lot of emphasis on
international economic arrangements. The Bretton Woods international order,
despite all of its weaknesses, created a framework in which governments had
considerable policy space to pursue full employment and egalitarian social
policies. When the developed nations shifted to floating exchange rates in
1973, it set in motion the enormous expansion in global capital movements that
undermined Keynesian economic management. That was the context in which market
fundamentalism became dominant.
But we could, once
again, reform the rules governing the global economy to expand the policy space
available to governments to protect people from economic volatility and
uncertainty. There is nothing inevitable about the current rules governing the
global economy. They represent a particular political settlement that urgently
needs to be revisited.
Shenk: One of the pleasures of reading this book—and
of reading all your work—is seeing the range of influences you draw upon. But
the dominant figure has to be Karl Polanyi (who you’ve written
about extensively before.) How would you situate this book in relation
to Polanyi—what are you drawing upon, and what are you pushing against?
Block: My core arguments in the book are certainly
Polanyian—that a self-regulating market system cannot possibly exist and that
actually existing market societies rely heavily on government action to make
markets work. But I also tried to avoid the Polanyian language of embeddedness
and disembeddedness in explaining the relationship between the economy and the
rest of society. I worry that those terms have become more confusing than
illuminating. For me the fundamental point that Polanyi was making is that the
economy cannot possibly be autonomous, let alone self-regulating.
Shenk: Reading this book, I couldn’t help but think of
Quinn Slobodian’s fantastic new book Globalists.
According to Slobodian, the founding neoliberals—economists like Friedrich
Hayek and Ludwig von Mises—shared Polanyi’s belief that the market couldn’t be
trusted to take care of itself. They thought providing markets with the right
institutional support was absolutely crucial, but they also thought that mass
democracy posed potentially fatal threat to these institutions. You, obviously,
take a different view. What do you think Hayek and von Mises got wrong?
Block: Here is another case where I think
Polanyi got it right. He insisted that while Hayek and von Mises constantly
proclaimed their antipathy to fascism, they had, in fact, paved the path for
its triumph. On the one side, they wanted the market to determine how much work
people were offered and how much they would be paid. On the other, they wanted
constraints on democracy, so that workers could not use their voting power to
win pensions and unemployment insurance. The consequence was that those who
faced high levels of economic instability could not use democratic institutions
to protect themselves. That was the context in which fascism developed and
ultimately triumphed. In a word, what Hayek and von Mises got wrong was that
they imagined that people would tolerate the instability and uncertainty that
lightly regulated markets inevitably produce.
What is so scary about
our current moment is that a new generation of free-market ideologues have
weakened democratic institutions by again blocking their use to protect people
from higher levels of economic uncertainty. This was most clear in Greece where
no matter how people voted, the European Community insisted
that Greece endure continuing austerity. But the same thing has been
happening around the world and it is the reason that authoritarianism is on the
march.
Shenk: I’ve been skeptical about the political
uses of “capitalism” for a long time, and for similar reasons to the ones you
outline here. Basically, I worry that by presenting a deceptively totalizing
system it tricks us into thinking the economic order is more coherent and
stable than it is, which reduces our choices to either socialist triumph or
total defeat. That fits, too, with your narrative of a concept that was born on
the radical left and then appropriated by the right to bludgeon its inventors
with. But lately I’ve been wondering if I’m wrong about this. It seems like
disillusionment with capitalism is leading more and more people toward
socialism, even if it’s a modest, Bernie-Sanders-style understanding of the
term. There’s a pragmatism here that cuts against the fear that using
“capitalism” dooms us to a totalizing program that inevitably leads to
disappointment. What do you think - having stolen the concept of capitalism from
the left, might conservatives come to regret their victory?
Block: Polanyi wrote that “Socialism is,
essentially, the tendency inherent in an industrial civilization to transcend
the self-regulating market by consciously subordinating it to a democratic
society.” By that definition, our existing society is already somewhat socialist
because of democratic reforms such as minimum wages, public schools, income
taxes, Social Security, and unemployment insurance. In other words, socialism
and extending democracy in the economy are the same thing. As you say, this is
pretty close to what people like Bernie Sanders and Jeremy Corbyn are talking
about.
But the great
advantage of focusing on democracy is that we can build a bridge that connects
moderate reforms such as universal health care to a vision of a society that is
much more egalitarian and democratic than anything that currently exists. It is
not utopian to talk about a society in which people are not bullied or
exploited by employers, by big corporations, or by government agencies because
there are effective democratic safeguards against arbitrary authority. Of
course, we will not end racism and sexism and the abuse of power any day soon,
but that idea of radical democracy is powerful enough to inspire people to
engage in a struggle that will take generations.
Shenk: Some of my favorite moments in the book were
the brief autobiographical asides where you note that back in the day you were
one of those New Left Marxists trying to force capitalism into the academic
(and, eventually, public) conversation. Can you take a moment to explain the
road that led you to here? What mistakes are you trying to stop younger
activists from making today? What lessons from your own experience do you think
are the most important to convey?
Block: As with many others, I joined the New
Left to end the Vietnam War and to fight racial inequality. I understood why
people in the movement turned toward revolutionary rhetoric and violence, but
it was profoundly mistaken as a political strategy. What we needed, instead,
were years of careful and patient organizing to build power from the bottom up.
That is what Bernie Sanders and his people did in Vermont. Had the same thing
happened in forty-nine other states, we would not today be facing Donald Trump
and a reactionary Supreme Court majority.
So my message to
younger activists is that it is possible to combine a radical vision of a
society in which people freely govern themselves with participation in
struggles for incremental reforms that do not buy people off but instead whet
their appetites to fight for more. And such mobilizations can weaken and
undermine class power and open space for an expansion of democracy.
https://www.dissentmagazine.org/online_articles/booked-interview-fred-block-capitalism-end-of-an-illusion